monoculturalist root什么意思思

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
This article has multiple issues. Please help
or discuss these issues on the . ()
This article needs additional citations for . Please help
by . Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (November 2011) ()
The examples and perspective in this article may not represent a
of the subject. You may , discuss the issue on the , or , as appropriate. (May 2014) ()
Cultural assimilation is the process by which a person's or group's culture come to resemble those of another group. The term is used to refer to both in the latter case can refer to either foreign
or native residents that come to be culturally dominated by another society.
Cultural assimilation may involve either a quick or gradual change depending on circumstances of the group. Full assimilation occurs when new members of a society become indistinguishable from members of the other group. Whether it is desirable for an immigrant group to assimilate is often disputed by both members of the group and those of the dominant society. Cultural assimilation does not guarantee social homophily though as this article states, geographical and other natural barriers between cultures even if started by the same dominant culture will be culturally different.
A place (a state or an ethnicity) can spontaneously adopt a different culture due to its political relevance, or to its perceived superiority. The first is the case of the
and culture, that were gradually adopted by most of the subjugated people.
Cultural assimilation can happen either spontaneously or forcibly. A culture can spontaneously adopt a different culture or older and richer cultures forcibly integrate other weak cultures. The term assimilation is often used with regard to immigrants and various ethnic groups who have settled in a new land. A new culture and new attitudes toward the origin culture are obtained through contact and communication.
is not simply a one-way process. Assimilation assumes that relatively tenuous culture gets to be united to one unified culture. This process happens through contact and accommodation between each culture. The current definition of assimilation is usually used to refer to immigrants, but in , cultural assimilation can happen all over the world, not just be limited to specific areas. For example, a shared language gives people the chance to study and work internationally, not just being limited to the same cultural group. People from different countries contribute to diversity and form the "global culture" which means the culture combined by the elements from different countries. This "global culture" can be seen as a part of assimilation that causes cultures from different areas to affect each other.
Immigrant assimilation is a complex process in which immigrants not only fully integrate themselves into a new country, but also lose aspects, perhaps all of their heritage too. Social scientists rely on four primary benchmarks to assess immigrant assimilation: , geographic distribution,
attainment, and . William A.V. Clark defines immigrant assimilation as "a way of understanding the social dynamics of American society and that it is the process that occurs spontaneously and often unintended in the course of interaction between majority and ".
Between 1880 and 1920, the United States took in roughly 24 million immigrants. This increase in immigration can be attributed to many historical changes. The beginning of the twenty-first century has also marked a massive era of immigration, and sociologists are once again trying to make sense of the impact that immigration has on society and the impact it has on immigrants themselves.
Assimilation had various meanings in American sociology,
associates American assimilation with Americanization or the melting pot theory. Some scholars also believed assimilation and acculturation were synonymous. According to a many's point of view, assimilation is a "process of interpretation and fusion" from another group or person. This may include memories, behaviors and sentiments. By sharing their experiences and histories, they blend into the common cultural life.
The long history of immigration in these established gateways means that the place of immigrants in terms of , , and
hierarchies in these traditional gateways are more structured or established on the other hand these new gateways do not have much immigration
therefore the place of immigrants in terms of class, racial, and ethnic hierarchies is less defined and immigrants may have more influence to define their position. Secondly, the size of new gateways may influence immigrant assimilation. Having a smaller gateway may influence the level of
among immigrants and native-born people. Thirdly, the difference in institutional arrangements may influence immigrant assimilation. Traditional gateways, unlike new gateways, have many institutions set up to help immigrants such as legal aid, bureaus, social organizations. Finally, Waters and Jimenez have only speculated that these differences may influence immigrant assimilation and the way researchers should assess immigrant assimilation.
Culture-specific:
(Assimilation of Australian Aborigines)
Parisi, Domenico, Federico Cecconi, and Francesco Natale. "Cultural change in spatial environments: the role of cultural assimilation and internal changes in cultures." Journal of Conflict Resolution 47.2 (2003): 163–179.
Waters, Mary C.; Jiménez, Tomás R. (2005). "Assessing Immigrant Assimilation: New Empirical and Theoretical Challenges". . 31 (1): 105–125. :.
Clark, W. (2003). Immigrants and the American Dream: Remaking the Middle Class. New York: Guilford Press.  .
Alba, Richard D.; Nee, Victor (2003). Remaking the American Mainstream. Assimilation and Contemporary Immigration. Harvard University Press.  .
Armitage, Andrew (1995). . UBC Press.  .
Crispino, James A. (1980). The Assimilation of Ethnic Groups: The Italian Case. Center for Migration Studies.  .
Drachsler, Julius (1920). Democracy and Assimilation: The Blending of Immigrant Heritages in America. Macmillan.
Gordon, Milton M. Daedalus Yetman, ed. "Assimilation in America: Theory and Reality". Journal of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences. Boston, Mass. 90 (2): 245–258.
Gordon, Milton M. (1964). Assimilation in American Life: The Role of Race, Religion, and National Origins. New York: Oxford University Press.
Grauman, Robert A. (1951). Methods of studying the cultural assimilation of immigrants. University of London.
Kazal, R. A. (April 1995). "Revisiting Assimilation". American Historical Society. 100.
Murguía, Edward (1975). Assimilation, Colonialism, and the Mexican American People. Center for Mexican American Studies. University of Texas at Austin.  .
Zhou, Min (Winter 1997). "Segmented Assimilation: Issues, Controversies, and Recent Research on the New Second Generation". International Migration Review. 31 (4, Special Issue: Immigrant Adaptation and Native–Born Responses in the Making of Americans).
(1998). : How Vietnamese Children Adapt to Life in the United States. vol. III. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.  .
: Hidden categories:Earlier versions of this paper have been presented at the Annual Meeting of the Flemish and Dutch Political Science Associations, Berg en Dal 2008, and the Summer University course 2008 "Complex Systems and Social Simulations", Central European University, Budapest. I would like to thank Sarah de Lange, David Hollanders, Niklas Lampenius, Erik Johnston, Ruud Koopmans, Susanne Rebers, Fleur Thom&se, Ralf Kaptijn and Jan Kleinnijenhuis for helpful comments and suggestions. Gaby Vullings (Interview/NSS) kindly provided data on public opinion support and Michael Laver was helpful by sending me his programming code.
The trade-off of ABMs is the cost of having less exacting analytics. Formal models are more precise. As McElreath and Boyd () put it: "There is comfort in vagueness, and formal theory allows for little comfort". But a hypothesis should not only be as precise as possible, but also give a best possible answer on a relevant question. Thus, I agree Miller and Page (: 71) that "analytic methods provide exact answers" but "good answers only make sense when we are asking good questions".
This critique on a solely theoretical application of recent agent-based models is similar to the criticism on sharp-end rational-choice theorists, that despite its theoretical sophistication, rational choice theory has been of little empirical use and empirical applications in the field have been rather unimpressive ().
I used Netlogo version 4.0.2. The programming code for the entire model is available on the author's .
Voters in a directional model have preferences for one side or the other with regard to an issue. A middle position reflects neutrality, not a certain position (). In practice, this implies the possibility that actor X is located at exactly the same place as party A, but would still prefer party B as it is located further away from the centre. Moreover, it is necessary to add a parameter (the 'region of acceptability') to penalize extremism, otherwise a right-wing moderate, for example, would prefer to vote for an extreme right, rather than for a right-wing moderate party. Aarts et al. () showed that the directional model slightly outperforms the proximity model in predicting party evaluations in the N however, their analysis is restricted to a selection of the four largest parties. In general, empirical support on which model best represents voting is ambiguous (see e.g. ).
The mean position of the parties is weighted by the share of vote won by the party in the 1998 election.
The formula for media distortion is as follows: Distortion = 3 - ln (1 + &Media attention)
In this case, the role of the media referred to effects of a party suffering from negative news, not from a shortage of attention.
Minor differences are due the fact that the election results and first opinion poll after the elections slightly differ.
Less risky steps of 0.5 instead 1.0 make the results somewhat better (MAD = 4.1 and MAD2 =
4.8) but are still worse than the basic ideological model.
In model A, the 'real' party size of the LPF is used for the calculating of the fit after the split- LN is 'missing' so not affecting the MAD.
An alternative model in which it is assumed that the CDA becomes an Aggregator or Hunter, in line with the idea that the reason for electoral success was the replacement of the party leader by the more adaptive Jan-Peter Balkenende who more strongly mobilized dissatisfaction with the multicultural society (), the party indeed slightly shifts on the y-axis. This model does not fare better as the move out of the centre supports the PvdA and D66 and severely harms Fortuyn.
Adjusting the simulation because of the fact that political campaigning was put aside after the assassination (by turning all media distortion off after that moment) is only significantly better when Liveable Netherlands is excluded (otherwise they become very large). The model fit for the election outcome is 4.40 and 5.34 (MAD and MAD2) and it is correctly estimated that the CDA is the winner (with about 22%).
References
K (2005) Dwarse kiezers. Enschede: Universiteit Twente.
K, MacDonald S E and Rabinowitz G (1999a) Issues and party competition in the Netherlands. Comparative Political Studies 32(1): 63-99
K, Van der Kolk H and Kamp M (1999b) Dutch Parliamentary Election Study, 1998 [Computer file]. Amsterdam: NIWI-Steinmetz Archive/Dutch Electoral Research Foundation (SKON).
K and Thomassen J (2008) Dutch voters and the changing party space . Acta Politica 43: 203-234.
M, Van der Brug W and Van Spanje J (2005) De kiezer op drift? In Brants K and Van Praag P (Eds), Politiek en media in verwarring. De verkiezingscampagnes in het lange jaar 2002. Amsterdam: Het Spinhuis. pp. 218-243.
R, Tilley J and Heath A F (2005) Political knowledge and enlightened preferences: party choice through the electoral cycle. British Journal of Political Science 35: 285-302.
R B and Irwin G A (2005) Governance and politics of the Netherlands (second edition). Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.
R (1984) The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Books.
R (1997) The complexity of cooperation. Agent-based models of competition and collaboration. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
F R and Jones B D (2002) Positive and negative feedback in politics. In Baumgartner F R and Jones B D (Eds.), Policy dynamics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. pp. 3-28.
E and Aarts K (2006) Explaining the rise of the LPF. Issues, discontent, and the
2002 Dutch Election. Acta Politica 41: 4-20.
J, Diermeier D and Ting M (2003) A behavioral model of turnout. American Political Science Review 97(2): 261-280.
K and Laver M (2006) Party policy in modern democracies. London: Routledge.
M (2003) Positive feedback in collective mobilization: the American strike wave of 1886. Theory and Society 32: 217-254
A, Nadeau R, Gidengil E and Nevitte N (2001) The formation of party preferences: testing the proximity and directional models. European Journal of Political Research 40: 81-91.
R and Squazzoni F (2005) Does empirical embeddedness matter? Methodological issues on agent-based models for analytical social science. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation 8 (4) 6
I (1994) A new spatial theory of party competition: uncertainty, ideology and policy equilibria viewed comparatively and temporally. British Journal of Political Science 24(4): 443-467
I, Klingemann H D, Volkens A, Bara J and Tanenbaum E (2001) Mapping policy preferences. Estimates for parties, electors, and governments . Oxford: Oxford University Press.
(Statistics Netherlands) (2006) The opinion of the Dutch population on the multicultural society . Data retrieved 1-9-2006 from
L E (2005) Computational models of social forms: advancing generative process theory. American Journal of Sociology 110(4): 864-93
J and De Galan M (2002) In de ban van Fortuyn. Reconstructie van een politieke aardschok. Amsterdam: Mets & Schilt.
M, Lubbers M and Scheepers P (2006) 'Het tolerante land' in historisch en in landenvergelijkend perspectief. In Van Tubergen F and Maas I (Eds.), Allochtonen in Nederland in internationaal perspectief. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press. pp. 89-110.
LANGE S (2007) A new winning formula? The programmatic appeal of the radical right. Party Politics 13(4): 411-435.
MARCHI S (1999) Adaptive models and electoral instability. Journal of Theoretical Politics 11(3): 393-419.
MARCHI S and Page, S E (2008) Agent-based modeling. In Box-Steffensmeier J M, Brady, H E and Collier D (Eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Political Methodology. Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp.71-94.
VRIES J and Van der Lubben S (2005) Een onderbroken evenwicht in de Nederlandse politiek. Paars II en de revolte van Fortuyn. Amsterdam: Van Gennep.
D C (1995) Darwin's dangerous idea. Evolution and the meanings of life. New York: Simon & Schuster.
A (1957) An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper & Row.
J M (1999) Agent-based computational models and generative social science. Complexity 4(5): 41-60.
[doi:10.1002/(SICI):53.0.CO;2-F]
M and Van der Brug W (2006) Nederlandse anti-immigratie partijen in Europees perspectief. In Van Tubergen F and Maas I (Eds.), Allochtonen in Nederland in internationaal perspectief. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press. pp. 63-87.
J H and Laver M (2008) A tournament of party decision rules. Journal of Conflict Resolution 52(1): 68-91.
J and Ruge M H (1965) The structure of foreign news. The presentation of the Congo, Cuba and Cyprus crises in four Norwegian newspapers. Journal of Peace Research 2: 64-91.
W A and Wolfsfeld G (1993) Movements and media as interacting systems. Annals of the American Academy of Political Science 528: 114-125.
A and King G (1993) Why are American presidential election campaign polls so variable when votes are so predictable? British Journal of Political Science 23: 409-451.
J C, Cosenza M G, Klemm K, Egu&luz V M and San Miguel M (2007) Information feedback and mass media effects in cultural dynamics. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation 10 (3) 9 .
D P and Shapiro I (1994) Pathologies of rational choice theory. A critique of applications in political science. New Haven: Yale University Press.
S and Bosk C L (1988) The rise and fall of social problems: A public arenas model. American Journal of Sociology 94: 53-78.
G A and Van Holsteyn J J M (2004) The 2002 and 2003 parliamentary elections in The Netherlands. Electoral Studies 23: 545-571.
M A and Ostrom E (2006) Empirically based, agent-based models. Ecology and Society 11(2) 37 .
R W (1999) How much is too much? Media attention and popular support for an insurgent party. Political Communication 16: 429-445.
H (1995) The radical right in Western Europe. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan.
J and Fan D P (1999) Media coverage and the flow of voters in multiparty systems: the 1994 National Elections in Holland and Germany. International Journal of Public Opinion Research 11(3): 233-256.
J, Oegema D, De Ridder J A, and Bos H (1995) De democratie op drift. Een evaluatie van de verkiezingscampagne van 1994. Amsterdam: VU Uitgeverij.
J, Oegema D, De Ridder J A and Ruigrok P C (1998) Paarse polarisatie: De slag om de kiezer in de media. Alphen aan den Rijn: Samson.
J, Oegema D, De Ridder J A, Van Hoof A and Vliegenthart R (2003) De puinhopen in het nieuws. De rol van de media bij de Tweede-Kamerverkiezingen van 2002. Alphen aan den Rijn: Kluwer.
J, Van Hoof A, Oegema D and De Ridder J A (2007) A test of rivaling approaches to explain news effects: news on issue positions of parties, real-world developments, support and criticism, and success and failure. Journal of Communication 57: 366-384.
K, Miller J H and Page S E (1992) Adaptive parties in spatial elections. American Political Science Review 86(4): 929-937.
K, Miller J H and Page S E (1998) Political parties and electoral landscapes. British Journal of Political Science 28: 139-158.
K, Miller J H and Page S E (2003) Introduction In Kollman K, Miller J H and Page S E (Eds.), Computational models in political economy. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press.
R (2004) Movements and media. Selection processes and evolutionary dynamics in the public sphere. Theory and Society 33: 367-391.
R and Muis J C (2009) The rise of right-wing populist Pim Fortuyn in the Netherlands. A discursive opportunity approach. European Journal of Political Research 48: 642-664.
H (2001) Die rolle der &Offentlichkeit im politischen Entscheidungsprozess. Ein konzeptueller Rahmen f&r ein international vergeleichendes Forschungsprojekt. Discussion paper P01-701. Berlin: Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin f&r Sozialforschung (WZB).
A (2003) De gedaantewisseling van politieke partijen. Een theoretisch ontwikkelingsmodel. In Jaarboek Nederlandse Politieke Partijen 2003. Groningen: Documentatiecentrum Nederlandse Politieke Partijen. pp. 138-172
A (2006) Party Models. In Katz R S and Crotty W (Eds.), Handbook of Party Politics. London: Sage. pp.249-269.
M (1995) Party policy and cabinet portfolios in the Netherlands, 1994. Results from an expert survey. Acta Politica 30:3-28.
M (2005) Policy and the dynamics of political competition. American Political Science Review 99(2): 263-281.
M (Ed.) (2001) Estimating the policy positions of political actors. London: Taylor & Francis.
M and Mair P (1999) Party policy and cabinet portfolios in the Netherlands, 1998. Results from an expert survey. Acta Politica 34: 49-66.
M and Schilperoord M (2007) Spatial models of political competition with endogenous political parties. Philosophical transactions of the Royal Society B 362: .
P (2000) Prophets, purifiers and prolocutors: towards a theory on the emergence of new parties. Party Politics 6(2): 175-185.
M (1997) Identity, interest and emergent rationality. An evolutionary synthesis. Rationality and Society 9: 427-448.
M and Willer R (2002) From factors to actors: computational sociology and agent-based modeling. Annual Review of Sociology 28: 143-166.
P (2008) Electoral volatility and the Dutch party system. A comparative perspective Acta Politica 43: 235-253
D, Tarrow S and Tilly C (2001) Dynamics of contention. New York: Cambridge University Press.
R and Boyd R (2007) Mathematical models of social evolution. A guide for the perplexed. Chicago: Chicago University Press.
J H and Page S E (2007) Complex adaptive systems. An introduction to computational models of social life. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
J (2002) De strijd om de macht. Politieke campagnes, idealen en intriges. Amsterdam: Prometheus.
P E and Myers D J (2003a) The coevolution of social movements. Mobilization 8(1): 1-12.
P E and Myers D J (2003b) Networks, diffusion, and cycles of collective action. In Diani M and McAdam D (Eds.), Social movement analysis: the network perspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp. 173-203.
PELLIKAAN H (2004) Partijen in een politieke ruimte. In Jaarboek Documentatiecentrum Nederlandse politieke partijen 2002. Groningen: Documentatiecentrum Nederlandse Politieke Partijen. pp. 206-229.
H, De Lange S and Van der Meer T (2007) Fortuyn's legacy: party system change in the Netherlands. Comparative European Politics 5: 282-302.
H, Van der Meer T and De Lange S (2003) The road from a depoliticized to a centrifugal democracy. Acta Politica: 38: 23-49.
P and Keman H (2003) The Dutch parliamentary elections in 2002 and 2003: The rise and decline of the Fortuyn movement. Acta Politica 38: 51-68.
K R (1973) Objective knowledge. An evolutionary approach. Oxford: Clarendon.
G and MacDonald S E (1989) A directional theory of issue voting. American Political Science Review 83(1): 93-121.
M L (2004) Political modeling and election simulations. Dr. Dobb's Journal: Software tools for the professional programmer 29(10): 16-27.
T C (1978) Micromotives and macrobehavior. New York: Norton & Company.
A and Soetenhorst B (2007) Daadkracht en duidelijkheid. Vijf jaar crisis in de VVD. Amsterdam: Van Gennep.
(Social and Cultural Planning Office of the Netherlands) (2003). Rapportage minderheden 2003. Onderwijs, arbeid en sociaal-culturele integratie. The Hague: SCP.
Y, Yasuno S and Ishiguro I (2001) Effects of global information feedback on diversity: extensions to Axelrod's adaptive culture model. Journal of Conflict Resolution 45: 80-96.
H A (1983) Reason in human affairs. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
P M and Hagendoorn L (2007) When ways of life collide. Multiculturalism and its discontents in the Netherlands. Princeton: Princeton University Press
A, Penzar D, Rodik P and Kardov K (2003) An agent-based model of ethnic mobilisation. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation 6(1) 1
J L, Jones B D and Baumgartner F R (2007) Punctuated-equilibrium theory. Explaining stability and change in public policymaking. In Sabatier P A (Ed.) Theories of the policy process. Boulder: Westview Press. pp. 155-187.
DER BRUG W (2007) Een crisis van de partijdemocratie? Amsterdam: Vossiuspers, Universiteit van Amsterdam.
DER BRUG W and Fennema M (2003) Protest or mainstream? How the European anti-immigrant parties developed into two separate groups by 1999. European Journal of Political Research 42: 55-76.
HOLSTEYN J J M and Irwin G A (2003) Never a dull moment: Pim Fortuyn and the Dutch parliamentary election of 2002. West European Politics 26(2): 41-66.
HOLSTEYN J J M, Irwin G A and Den Ridder J M (2003) In the eye of the beholder. The perception of the List Pim Fortuyn and the parliamentary elections of May 2002. Acta Politica 38: 69-87.
KERSBERGEN K (2008) The Christian Democratic Phoenix and modern unsecular politics. Party Politics 14(3): 259-279.
PRAAG P (2003) The winners and losers in a turbulent political year. Acta Politica 38: 5-22.
H (2004) De erfenis van Fortuyn. De Nederlandse democratie na de opstand van de kiezers. Amsterdam: Meulenhoff.
D J (2003) Six degrees. The science of a connected age. New York: W.W. Norton & Company.
Export citation
Articles with the same author(s)
Articles with similar keywords
Articles citing this article
Alert me when this article is cited within JASSS
Your email:
Send a link to this article to a colleague
Your name:
Your email:
Your colleague&s email:}

我要回帖

更多关于 root什么意思 的文章

更多推荐

版权声明:文章内容来源于网络,版权归原作者所有,如有侵权请点击这里与我们联系,我们将及时删除。

点击添加站长微信